參考文獻 |
[1] Asness, C. S., R. B. Porter, and R. L. Stevens (2000). “Predicting stock returns using industry-relative firm characteristics." Working paper, Goldman Sachs Asset Management, Quantitative Research Group.
[2] Banz, R. W. (1981). “The relationships between return and market value of common stocks." Journal of Financial Economics 6, 103-126.
[3] Barberis, N., A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny (1998). “A model of investor sentiment." Journal of Financial Economics 49, 307-343.
[4] Black, F. (1972). “Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing." Journal of Business 45, 444-455.
[5] Black, F., M. C. Jensen, and M. Scholes (1972). “The capital asset pricing model: some empirical tests, in M. Jensen, ed.: Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets (Praeger)."
[6] Black, F. (1993). “Beta and return." Journal of Portfolios Management 20, 8-18.
[7] Chen, N.-F., R. Roll, and S. A. Ross (1986). “Economic forces and the stock market." Journal of Business 59, 383-403.
[8] Chordia, T. and L. Shivakumar (2002). “Momentum, business cycle, and time-varying expected returns." Journal of Finance 57, 985-1019.
[9] Chou, P.-H. (2003). “Implied equilibrium in the CAPM." unpublished manuscript, National Central University, Taiwan.
[10] Chou, P.-H. (2003). “On the role of industry in the cross-section and time-series of stock returns." NSC proposal, National Central University, Taiwan.
[11] Daniel, K., and S. Titman (1997). “Evidence on the characteristics of cross sectional variation in stock returns." Journal of Finance 52, 1-33.
[12] Danel, K., D. Hirshleifer, and A. Subrahmanyam (1998). “Investor psychology and security market under- and overreactions." Journal of Finance 53, 1839-1886.
[13] Fama, E. F., and J. D. MacBeth (1973). “Risk, Return and Equilibrium: Empirical tests." Journal of Political Economy 81, 607-636.
[14] Fama, E. F., and K. R. French (1992). “The cross-section of expected stock returns." Journal of Finance 47, 427-465.
[15] Fama, E. F., and K. R. French (1993). “Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds." Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3-56.
[16] Fama, E. F., and K. R. French (1996). “Multifactor explanations of asset pricing anomalies." Journal of Finance 51, 55-84.
[17] Fama, E. F., and K. R. French (1997). “Industry costs of equity." Journal of Financial Economics 43, 153-193.
[18] Fiegenbaum, A. (1990). “Prospect theory and the risk-return association: An empirical examination in 85 industries." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 14,
187-203.
[19] Fiegenbaum, A. and H. Thomas (1988). “Attitudes toward risk and the risk-return paradox: Prospect theory explanations." Academy of Management Journal 31, 85-106.
[20] Gibbons, M., S. A. Ross, and J. Shanken (1989). “Testing the efficiency of a given portfolio." Econometrica 57, 1121-1152.
[21] Grundy, B. D. and J. S. Martin (2001). “Understanding the Nature of the Risks and the Source of the Rewards to Momentum Investing." Review of Financial Studies 14,29-78.
[22] Hong, H., and J. C. Stein (1999). “A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading, and overreaction in asset markets." Journal of Finance 54, 2143-2184.
[23] Hong, H., W. Torous, and R. Valkanov (2002). “Do industries lead the stock market."
Working paper, Princeton University.
[24] Hou, K. (2003). “Industry information diffusion and the lead-lag effect in stock returns." Working Paper, Ohio State University.
[25] Hou, K., and D. T. Robison (2003). “Industry concentration and average stock returns." Working paper, Ohio State University.
[26] Kahle, K. M., and R. A. Walkling (1996). “The impact of industry classifications on financial research." Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31, 309-335.
[27] Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky (1979). “Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk." Econometrica 47, 263-291.
[28] Knez, P. J. and M. J. Ready (1997). “On the robustness of size and book-to-market in cross-sectional regressions." Journal of Finance 52, 1355-1382.
[29] Lakonishok, J., A. Shleifer, and R. W. Vishny (1994). “Contrarian investment, extrapolation, and risk." Journal of Finance 49, 1541-1578.
[30] Lewellen, J. (2002). “Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns." Review of Financial Studies 15, 533-563.
[31] Lintner, J. (1965). “The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets." Review of Economics and Statistics 47, 13-37.
[32] Merton, R. C. (1973). “An intertemporal capital asset pricing model." Econometrica 41, 867-887.
[33] Moskowitz, T. J. and M. Grinblatt (1999). “Do industries explain momentum." Journal of Finance 54, 1249-1290.
[34] Newey, W. K., and K. D. West (1987). “A simple heteroskedastic and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix." Econometrica 55, 703-708.
[35] Roll, R. (1977). “A critique of the asset pricing theory's tests: On past and potential testability of the theory." Journal of Financial Economics 4, 129-176.
[36] Ross, S. A. (1976). “The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing." Journal of Economic Theory 13, 341-360.
[37] Sharpe, W. F. (1964). “Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk." Journal of Finance 19, 425-442. |